Should the US Reform Interchange Fees on Credit Cards?

(Cross Posted. I still don’t have a good idea why fees are increasing. The obvious mechanism, that rewards are increasing, wasn’t stated by any credit card company representatives I spoke to on background, even when directly asked. I think they want to stick with the story that they aren’t increasing, though that seems more a statistical illusion from the way charges are shifting from credit to debit. As I told one person, don’t try and trick financial engineers on illusionary averages – you need 2/3rds of the distribution to do that, I only need one percent of the tail!

People point out that cost of handling cash is high, which is fair, but I need to see evidence that it is rising. And even then, it doesn’t explain why a service so dependent on communication technology – handling a credit card transaction – is increasing in cost when there’s been a revolution in this field. Also the anti-business argument, that consumers wouldn’t benefit from interchange fee crackdowns, really misses that businesses are the consumers of financial services here.

Truth On The Market is going to have a blog symposium on interchange next week, with some big name heavy hitters. I hope they expand on the “two-sided market” issue, addressed by the GAO report, and how that market structure influences the competitive landscape between customers and business owners, and hopefully something I’ll get a good blog description of in advance.)

Last week, the Government Accounting Office issued a report on interchange fees, with the summary right there in the title: “Rising Interchange Fees Have Increased Costs for Merchants, but Options for Reducing Fees Pose Challenges.” (links: full document, 1 page summary) Before we get to the big findings, what is an interchange fee, anyway? From the report:

When a consumer uses a credit card to make a purchase, the merchant does not receive the full purchase amount because a certain portion of the sale is deducted and distributed among the merchant’s financial institution, the financial institution that issued the card, and the card network that processes the transaction. The majority of this amount generally is called the interchange fee and goes to the financial institution that issued the card. As card use has become more popular, the costs for merchants of accepting them have been rising, and considerable debate has been occurring over these costs, and particularly the level of interchange fee rates.

So what does this look like? Let’s look at a diagram of this process broken down (click to enlarge):

You charge $100 with a credit card. The store has a hypothetical contract with his bank that has a 2.20% merchant discount rate and the bank affiliated with your credit card has a 1.7% interchange fee. So your bank collects 1.7% of your charge, while the store’s bank collects 2.2 – 1.7 = 0.5%.

Now according to Federal Reserve analysis used by the GAO report, these fees have been going up. Looking at a chart from the GAO report, we can see the change in interchange fees over the past ten and twenty years (click to increase):

These numbers are reflective of domestic credit cards. The number of different categories a business could use have increased greatly since 1991. Visa went from 4 to 60, and Mastercard from 4 to 243. Critics argue that some of these increases in categories are to confuse and overwhelm merchants. But it makes sense that the credit card companies would need more specific and targeted categories over this time period since people are using credit cards for many more different types of purchases, including government, utilities, groceries, and online purchases, that they weren’t using in 1991. As such, the credit card companies want a variety of options to be able to target the needs of a variety of businesses.

Since so much more activity is online, and online purchases can be more risky, we don’t necessarily want to be watching the average to see if it is increasing or decreasing. We want to watch the change within categories. We normally associate innovation with decreasing fees, costs and profits as an industry matures. From this chart, we can see within categories, around 44% of rates increased over time, with only 12% decreasing.

What are the arguments for why this would increase? Sources from the credit card industry explained to me that the important thing to watch is the “effective rate” of all cards, which is the average in all cards, and that this hasn’t changed over time. What’s important to realize is that debit cards have less of a rate associated with them, and more people are switching to debit cards. However, as Felix Salmon noted, you can have the “effective rate” stay the same, or even fall, during a time period where all or some of the rates are increasing by having people switch to the lower rate.

This is, in Steve Waldman’s phrasing, a move from transactional and revolving credit, and that is a move that could benefit consumers who have trouble managing revolving debt. It is worthwhile to know that the credit card bill passed earlier this year doesn’t cover debit cards, and it is possible that fees and traps there could increase faster to compensate for the changes to the credit card industry.

What To Do?

Is it worthwhile to do anything about this situation? Critics like to point out that Australia recently capped interchange fees, and as one blog has summarized recent research, it “had the opposite effect of those that regulators were expecting. Retail prices are not lower. Instead, merchants enjoy stronger margins thanks to the lower cost of accepting cards.” Indeed some industry insiders have spoken with skepticism on this situation, saying that the real benefiters from increased scrutiny in this area wouldn’t be small businesses and consumers, but big box retailers.

I think this reflects a poor conceptualization of the credit card process. The business is the consumer of financial services too. So to say consumers haven’t benefited from interchange fee scrutiny because businesses enjoy better margins is wrong, as the business is precisely the consumer who has benefitted.

In their conclusion, the GAO Report remains skeptical that the problem is so big, or that the government’s tools are so strong, that action should be taken. They investigate the pros and cons of each of the following four options in detail in the appendix, and if the topic is of interest to you I’d recommend checking them out: (1) setting or limiting interchange fees, (2) requiring their disclosure to consumers, (3) prohibiting card networks from imposing rules on merchants that limit their ability to steer customers away from higher-cost cards, and (4) granting antitrust waivers to allow merchants and issuers to voluntarily negotiate rates.

Financial Literacy

I want to focus on #2 – requiring their disclosure to consumers. Advocates propose that consumers deserve to know since they carry part of the cost, and that this would be a non-intrusive market mechanism-based approached that would have consumers express their preferences better. Critics say that the information would possibly confuse consumers, and that it would be too complicated for a cashier to clearly communicate the correct interchange fee for each specific transaction.

This strikes me as one place where financial literacy could really do work here. Why not inform consumers of what is going on with interchange fees? They may ultimately not do anything about it; they may end up spending more as they’ll realize they are subsidizing credit card users if they do not use a credit card, so they might as well join in.

I would like to see a section of new financial literacy programs to include this topic. It goes undeveloped at Visa’s new Financial Football page. The only mention is an old press release from the 2008 gas price market, noting “To help ease the pain at the pump, Visa recently capped the per-transaction interchange fee for Visa-branded consumer debit card purchases at $0.95 per transaction.” (See this wonky take on that that translates.) Surprisingly for an educational site, it doesn’t mention that, according to creditcards.com, competitor Mastercard took actions the previous year to cap interchange rates on gas prices as well.

Some examples, say a grocer runs a $2m business with a 4% profit margin, 80% sales on credit cards with an X% fee, and the owner can’t pass costs on to consumers. What’s the owner’s salary with a 0% fee and a 2% fee? ($80,000 and $33,600). What if the fee goes to 2.2%? (His salary goes to $31,680.) Or maybe an example I hear from small businesses, where someone charges a $1 newspaper with a credit card, and the business loses money. When we swipe our cards, banks and credit card companies swipe some of the money. People deserve to see the effects their decisions have on businesses, themselves, and the market economy itself.

This entry was posted in Uncategorized. Bookmark the permalink.

5 Responses to Should the US Reform Interchange Fees on Credit Cards?

  1. noompa says:

    Really informative. I do have one question though- how effective do you see financial literacy being in this case? Granted, the interchange fees are ultimately being passed on to the consumer, but does the average consumer care enough to think that his use of a credit card is indirectly making his purchase more expensive? It seems to me that consumers would be just as likely to simply view interchange fees as something that businesses have to deal with, without focusing on the trickle-down effects that affect them (the consumers that is). That was part of the thinking driving the misconception of the Australian example, right? Just the other day, a friend of mine was complaining about cash-only late-night food joints. I mentioned the issue of interchange fees that both the restaurants and consumers have to deal with, and he didn’t seem overly bothered. The reason? “Its just so much more convenient though.” How many people would be willing to just brush the interchange fees under the carpet when it comes to convenience?

  2. CommonSense says:

    Great fact-based discussion. A couple of follow-ups to questions you raise in your blog. Costs for processing cash and check are going DOWN while costs for processing credit and debit are going UP! Here are the facts: Lots of strides have been made in processing of cash led by…the casino industry. We’ve all seen the cash counting machines that sorts through individual bills one at a time, but now they’ve gone farther and they can actually weigh cash on scales and tell how many bills are there. You see this at places like ChuckECheese too where they weich your tickets instead of counting them. Wal-Mart and other grocery stores are already starting to use the cash scales in order to speed up the handling time. Regarding checks, efficiencies continue to appear for processing paper checks which is supposedly a dying tender. ACH clearing now lets checks clear for less than a penny per check and the Cashier hands the check back to the customer which eliminates any back-office processing at all. That means if for a $100 sales a retailer accesses a customer’s checking account with a paper check, it will cost them less than 1 penny, but if they access it with a debit card, it will cost them closer to $1.50. Huh? What? Isn’t electronic supposed to be more efficient? Using that math, that’s like paying 41 cents for a stamp for a letter or paying $61.50 to send an email. Where’s the common sense in that? If you are looking for some source data, check out the presentation that WalMart made at the Chicago Federal Reserve back in May 2009.

  3. Ben says:

    Two things:
    – I can’t see financial literacy having _any_ impact. At the very best it’s a wash for consumers…at worst, consumers trade their fractional “reward points” for the merchant’s interchange fee…or worse (next point)

    – Credit cards come with “fraud protection”, but it’s not really fraud protection – it’s more like forceful fraud risk transfer. As a small merchant, if my company wants to sell on the internet, we have to take plastic so that consumers feel safe.

    But…how does the fraud protection work? Simple: if a user files a fraud complaint, the credit card company reverses the charge and then hits us (the merchant) with a fee (which is nearly as large as the cost of the product – I think my boss told me it’s around $30).

    If it happens to be that a user purchased $500 of inventory, had it shipped to his house, and then claims someone else used his card, there’s no investigation, and we (the merchant) definitely don’t get our inventory back.

    My rant here about fraud applies in two ways:
    – The fraud risk transfer behavior of cards is a benefit of consumer – the card companies use their leverage over the market place to enforce terms that are detrimental to merchants – but beneficial to consumers. (The consumer is effectively getting a fraud insurance policy without paying a premium – the cost is born on the merchant.) That free insurance probably outways any desire to help a merchant out with interchange fees.
    – The actual cost of credit card processing to merchants may be higher than the interchange fees – there are also fraud costs, or rather, the cost of participating in a system where the premium on fraud insurance is paid out by a party other than the beneficiary.

    This all strikes me as a poorly designed market-place…one that cannot reward fraud protection and that cannot control interchange costs.

    • Rebecca Z. says:

      the anti-business argument, that consumers wouldn’t benefit from interchange fee crackdowns, really misses that businesses are the consumers of financial services here.

      My local food co-op/health food store accepts credit cards. But they also have a sign on the counter explaining how much it costs, and asking you to pay cash. I never used to carry cash around, only my credit and debit cards. Thanks to that sign, I nearly always carry some cash to use it in my favorite shops. My guess is that we’re going to see a move toward cash purchases, driven by businesses and in response to the usurious transaction fees.

      Right now, I think credit-card companies forbid merchants from splitting the cost of the credit-card transaction fee with the consumer in exchange for a cash payment. Yet changing this would, I suspect, correct the market, and result in a more-informed consumer less apt to use credit unnecessarily.

      And such a change just might give the place-based store a small edge over the internet shop.

  4. Ron Stone says:

    Nice article. I agree with your suggestion of more disclosures to consumers. But to me, no matter what is said, the underlying reason these fees are going up is to make up for other areas of shortfall. There is also the hope that since the fees are small percentage wise that a 5%, 10% or more (small percent of a small percent) will go pretty much unnoticed.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s